Wilhelm Röpke infused his detailed analyses of modernity with a sensitive respect for the values of tradition and religious faith and their critical importance in building social and economic order
Born in 1899 in Schwarmstedt
Wilhelm Röpke would become one of the most distinguished economists of his age
Acknowledged as a worthy peer by such eminents as Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich A
Röpke was a key intellectual architect of postwar prosperity in Europe
economic director in postwar West Germany (and later chancellor of the Federal Republic)
unabashedly credited Röpke as the most formative single influence on his policies
Wilhelm Röpke made it his life’s work to help construct and defend the free society
to diagnose the ills of capitalism and suggest concrete solutions
Like a stern country doctor—his father’s profession—Röpke was never shy about criticizing the abuses of the body politic which endangered its health and rendered it defenseless against infections from far Right and Left
when he wrote about the abuses that had encrusted two centuries of capitalist practice
culminating in the crisis of the Great Depression
He sharply criticized the pro-business parties of Weimar Germany that supposedly stood for economic freedom but relied on the state to impose protectionism and shore up monopolies
had given credibility to the Marxist charge that market economics were merely an ideology
a rhetorical construct that served the class interests of the bourgeoisie
which violated its principles the moment they proved inconvenient
Röpke found common ground both with socialists and libertarians in exposing the inconsistencies of contemporary capitalism
He shared with socialists their outrage at hypocrisy
and social injustice; along with libertarians he held a deep respect for the wealth-creating free market
But he departed from both in his analysis of where the West had gone astray and what measures must be taken to restore Europe to health
Röpke seconded complaints made by counterrevolutionary thinkers on the Right
He too was appalled at the brutality and suddenness with which old lifestyles and mores had been uprooted through the political and economic revolutions that swept Europe after 1789
Röpke infused his detailed analyses of modernity with a sensitive respect for the values of tradition and religious faith and their critical importance in building social and economic order
Röpke’s work eludes easy categorization and repays careful reading and rereading by students of history
regardless of where their intellectual sympathies may lie
Röpke was a master of many languages and vernaculars; well-versed in technical economics
he has aptly been called a Renaissance man
While signs of this learning bejewel his books—including lengthy Latin and French quotes given in the old style
humane erudition—which Röpke reveals incidentally
while simply trying to make a point—may well have saved him from the intellectual extremes to which so many of his fellow social reformers fell prey
It also partly explains the breadth of his influence among educated Europeans like Ludwig Erhard
One of the first writers exiled by the Nazis for his ideas
Röpke subsequently worked in Turkey and Switzerland
writing books that helped preserve the spark of free thought in Germany and throughout occupied Europe
Röpke was one of the founding thinkers of the newly created Christian Democratic movement
the strongest European voice for resistance to the next totalitarian menace
While remaining a strong advocate of the free market
Röpke was also a keen critic of its abuses and an advocate for minimalist
effective intervention by the state to preserve vital social goods neglected by markets
it was Röpke who first coined the (later much-abused) term “the Third Way” to denote a market-friendly
socially responsible economic policy—one aimed at encouraging the widespread ownership of property
and small business throughout the population
Röpke considered the economic power of colossal corporations almost as dangerous as the political might of collectivist governments
and respect for traditional peoples and ways of life
he was an outspoken advocate of allowing Japan to retain her monarchy after the Second World War.) Ever a foe of nationalism
Röpke pointed to the eighteenth century as the zenith of European civilization—before ideas were branded by their country of origin and yoked to the service of intolerant nation-states
suspicious as any Swiss peasant of imperial governments
Röpke opposed attempts to abolish borders and concentrate power in the hands of transnational bureaucracies
Just as the market economy had been built by small businessmen
and entrepreneurs—at the expense of monopolists
and rationalist philosophes—so Röpke saw international order and liberty as arising from free regions federated within nation-states
whose relations must be governed by written or unwritten standards of international law and enforced by a balance of power
In light of the tragic failure of the post-Versailles commissions appointed to protect ethnic minorities in Europe
Röpke saw extra-governmental institutions (such as churches and civic and social organizations
often maintained by local elites) as the best defenders of human dignity against oppression by intolerant majorities
he was inspired by the example near at hand—the healthy diversity and peculiarity of Switzerland
whose liberties had grown not from international guarantees or utopian schemes
and ancient privileges fiercely guarded by peasant militias over centuries
Instead of a multinational currency administered by a central authority (like today’s Euro)
Röpke favored a worldwide gold standard that offered a single touchstone of value for many currencies—and wrested the critical power over the money supply from the hands of politicians and financial elites
leaving it to move spontaneously with the billions of daily decisions made by free men and women in free markets
making clear the workings of the market economy in writings aimed at the educated layman
American editions of his major works have remained in print for decades
and several neglected titles have been or soon will be reprinted in English
Röpke understood that economics had been irreversibly politicized; there was no going back to the old
nineteenth-century view that had placed the function of a nation’s productive capacities entirely beyond the reach of popular sovereignty
the mobilization of millions of men of every social class during the First World War
rising nationalist sentiment and class mistrust—all these currents had joined to overwhelm the levee behind which classical liberals had hoped to protect economic life from the turbulence of politics
No longer would it be enough to convince the economics professors
and the responsible classes of the virtues of a free market
The featured image by the Ludwig von Mises Institute is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-Share Alike 3.0 Unported license, courtesy of Wikimedia Commons
All comments are moderated and must be civil
Comments that are critical of an essay may be approved
but comments containing ad hominem criticism of the author will not be published
comments containing web links or block quotations are unlikely to be approved
Keep in mind that essays represent the opinions of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of The Imaginative Conservative or its editor or publisher
Money has always tempted the heads of state and their councils
post WW One was such an example and what a mess was made
and website in this browser for the next time I comment
Δdocument.getElementById( "ak_js_1" ).setAttribute( "value"
Δdocument.getElementById( "ak_js_2" ).setAttribute( "value"
The Imaginative Conservative is sponsored by The Free Enterprise Institute (a U.S
Your donation to the Institute in support of The Imaginative Conservative is tax deductible to the extent allowed by law
Your request has been blocked by our security system due to potential security concerns
Please contact us for assistance.